May’s theorem (majority rule uniquely satisfies anonymity, neutrality, and positive responsiveness for two options). (Overview) (
Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy)
Condorcet jury theorem (under independence and p>0.5, majority accuracy → 1 as n grows). (
math.chalmers.se)
McKelvey–Schofield chaos theorem (in multidimensional policy spaces, majority rule is generically unstable; agenda control can reach almost any point). (
Wikipedia)
Riker’s size principle (coalitions tend to be minimal winning under standard assumptions). (
Wikipedia)
Veto player theory (Tsebelis) (more veto players/greater ideological spread ⇒ higher policy stability). (
Wikipedia)
Pivotal politics (Krehbiel) (gridlock and lawmaking hinge on pivotal legislators relative to filibuster/veto pivots). (
University of Chicago Press)
Collective action, parties, & political sociology
#
Iron law of oligarchy (Michels) (organizational tendencies toward oligarchic control). (
Wikipedia)
Selectorate theory (Bueno de Mesquita et al.) (incentives from selectorate vs. winning coalition sizes). (
Wikipedia)
May’s law of curvilinear disparity (party activists more extreme than voters and leaders). (
Wikipedia)
Democratic peace (empirical regularity) (mature democracies rarely fight each other; various mechanisms posited). (
electowiki.org)
Holmström (1979) “informativeness principle” (any signal informative about action should enter optimal contracts). (
Duke People,
NBER)
Holmström (1982) “moral hazard in teams” (team production ⇒ free‑riding; budget‑balance typically incompatible with first‑best incentives). (
Duke People,
JSTOR)
Myerson–Satterthwaite theorem (bilateral trade with private values cannot be efficient, budget‑balanced, IR, and IC simultaneously). (
Wikipedia)
DeGroot learning (iterated weighted‑average updates converge to a consensus weighted by eigenvector centrality under connectivity/aperiodicity). (
Wikipedia)
(Related pointers) Mathematical models of social learning overview; information cascades. (
Wikipedia)